Solow Model

Submitted By RyanKirkley1
Words: 3100
Pages: 13

Handout 4 The Solow Model: Basic Concepts 1 The Solow model with no population growth and no technological change
1.1 Deriving the basic Solow equation

The Solow model is one of the simplest models one can use to explain economic growth. Represent a country’s aggregate production funciton by  =  ( ) ( )1− (1)

where for each time period   is gross domestic product (GDP),  is the capital stock level and  is the size of the labor force. To derive the Solow model, we begin with a very simple expression: +1 =  −  +  (2a)

This equation "says:" The level of the capital stock tomorrow (+1 ) is equal to the level of the capital stock today ( ), minus the capital stock lost through depreciation during period  ( ), plus investment in period  ( ). Note that     and  are called variables, while    and  are called parameters. To derive the Solow equation we make two assumptions. First, we assume that investment today is exactly equal to savings today. Another (shorthand) way of writing this is  =  This equation simply says investment in period  is exactly equal to savings in period  The second assumption is that the rate of savings is constant over time. Is this a reasonable assumption? Figures 1 and 2 show that savings rates are relatively stable for some countries and not for others. In figure 1, Australia and Belgium have relatively constant savings rates from the 1990s through 2008, while the savings rate for Costa Rica is stable from the mid 80s through the mid 90s, then increases between 1995 and 2000 and drops again after 2000. In figure 2, the U.S. and U.K. have savings rates that appear to have drifted downwards over time. Savings rates in the U.S. fell from around 20% in 1980 to 13% in 2007.

1

Savings Rates
30 25 20 15 10 5 0

Australia

Belgium

Costa Rica

Figure 1. Savings rates

Savings Rates
25 20 15 10 5 0

UK

US

High Income

Figure 2. Savings rates

2

One can conclude that the constant savings rate assumption can be quite reasonable for some countries, but problematic for others. In practical, applied work, one would likely use the average savings rate for the last ten or twenty years. Returning to the Solow model, with the constant savings assumption, investment in period  is equal to  =  =  where  is a constant savings rate. Substituting (1) into equation (3) gives  =  ( ) ( )1− which, substituted into equation (2a) yields +1 =  −  +  = (1 − )  +  ( ) ( )1− (4) (3)

For the moment, assume the labor force is constant. We can represent this by writing  =  for all  Then equation (4) can be written as +1 = (1 − )  +  = (1 − )  +  ( ) 1− To get the Solow equation, we now divide the above expression by  to get µ ¶ µ ¶1− +1  ( ) 1−    = (1 − ) +  = (1 − ) +        or +1 = (1 − )  +  ( ) where  =
 

(5)

is capital stock per unit of labor.

1.2

Working with the Solow equation

Equation (5) is the basic Solow model — i.e., the Solow model without labor force growth and technical change. It has the exact same meaning as equation (2a): i.e., "the capital stock in period  + 1 is equal to the capital stock in period , less the capital stock lost through depreciation, plus new investment. 1.2.1 The steady state

In class we observed that (5) is a difference equation in   A difference equation (for our purposes) tells us how the level of a variable in time  depends on the level of that variable in period  − 1 3

Here, the Solow equation gives us the level of the capital stock in period  as a function of the capital stock level in period  − 1 An important concept associated with difference equations is the steady state. A steady state is a level of a variable such that the level of that variable in period  is exactly equal to the level of that variable in period  − 1 In other words, for the basic Solow